Wednesday 21 February 2007

Under the old regime

Looking through some of my old stuff, I thought that a useful approach might be to "recycle" material from the past, updating it where necessary. Of course, some material does not need updating, since the situation it refers to has passed away. However, the definitions and tools may be of continuing use.

Repressed inflation in STEs
The interlinked phenomena of inflation and shortage in Soviet-type economies (STEs) can be attributed to a number of causes. Inflation is the movement of the aggregate price level for goods and services across the economy as a whole, although, when looking at causes, it is sometimes helpful to distinguish between those that are "one-off" in nature, originating from "outside" the normal workings of the economic system (for example, from mistakes of economic policy, or exogenous shocks, such as a rise in energy prices or a bad harvest), and those that are systemic, when the conditions behind the rise in the aggregate price level are constantly reproduced from within.

Causes of inflationary pressure under state socialism
In the classical model of state socialism, the system-specific causes of inflationary pressure may be listed as follows.

  • Persistent labour shortages put upward pressure on wages which, if reflected in actual wage increases for the economy as a whole, will tend to increase production costs.
  • As producer-sellers, firms have some vested interest in raising prices.
  • Operation of a passive monetary policy may lead to some uncontrolled growth in the money supply.
  • There is persistent excess demand at a macro level.
The last of these, excess macroeconomic demand, exerts the strongest inflationary pressure. And although there are also variations in the degree of excess demand prevalent in different sectors of the economy, it is most powerful in the state inter-firm sphere.

From this perspective, perhaps the most important phenomenon to understand is the process of taut or overfull employment planning. This is when the output plan for the enterprise is deliberately set above the firm's production capacity. The aim is to "seek out" resources; for individual managers, increased physical output is also the criteria for promotion. The effects, however, are that firms try to cut corners—for example, by reducing product quality or raising costs. From the point of view of structural constraints on the firm, this presents few problems, since the question of exit of firms from production is not an economic decision but a bureaucratic-political one. The peculiarity of the state property form means that, while in theory it is owned by everyone, in practice, "no one has a true inner interest in ensuring caution in handling money".

Soft budgets, passive money
In effect, the regime of the output plan means that a firm's budget is not a strict restriction on its access to resources. If a transaction seems to be demanded by the plan, a cheque—even one in excess of the firm's budget—will be cleared. Herein lies the "soft" character of financial budgets at enterprise level, and also the "passive" character of money in the inter-firm sphere. "Money" in this sense exists only as an accounting unit and does not exert any buying power. The total monetary demand for firms follows the financing needs of the plan. This is the reason why the term "excess demand" is sometimes considered inappropriate, and we should use the term remembering that it is compromised by the non-market character of the transactions involved. For this reason monetary and fiscal policy has no effect on the level of output. The rationale for Kornai’s observation that the firm under the classical socialist model has no particular interest in limiting its demand for inputs is thus seen to flow from the imposition of “taut” planning.

What symptoms when prices are controlled?
In STEs the symptoms of inflationary pressure are revealed by means other than price rises. This leads us to the question of repressed inflation, which may be introduced by a method of contrast. For while inflationary pressure may lead to a rise in the aggregate price level (open inflation), or actual rises in the prices of goods and services may not find their way into the calculation of the inflation index (hidden inflation), repressed inflation is said to exist when upward pressure on the price level is resisted by administrative control. (It is also defined by Nuti as the rate of change of excess demand.)

In the consumer goods market, too?
First, the boundaries of the debate must be delimited by saying that while the existence of excess demand in the state inter-firm sector of STEs is rarely challenged, the question of the endemic nature of repressed inflation in the market for consumer goods has been hotly debated. Also, the credit expansion typically exhibited in the state inter-firm sector would not have inflationary effects in the consumption sphere unless the (usually strict) separation of the functions of money between the two began to break down—if, for example, enterprise credit was allowed to be used to pay for wage increases and it became someone's income (ie if it was “activised”).

How, then, are we to identify inflation if movements in the price level are ruled out? To those who argue that repressed inflation is endemic to the consumer goods market, the evidence seems obvious: the chronic existence of queues, of shortages and of black-markets. These phenomena seem to testify to real attempts to consume more than is officially being produced. This is the kind of thinking adopted by Kornai in his attempt to construct an "index or partial indicators" from, for example, the number of building orders refused, unfulfilled car orders, or the length of waiting lists for accommodation. Pindak takes an equally direct approach to an analysis of Czechoslovakia between 1972 and 1978 by tracking the decreasing proportions of goods in the market for foodstuffs and industrial products not experiencing supply problems.

Another approach is to look at trends in saving. The theory here is that if consumers cannot make their desired purchases, and the bureaucracy prevents a rise in retail prices that would choke off demand, it is likely to be reflected in the rapid and involuntary growth of savings in relation to income or sales. However, since it is difficult to detect a change in the savings rate which signifies the qualitative change from voluntary to involuntary saving, some observers have pointed to the growth of the money-income ratio in many STEs as evidence of involuntary saving (and hence repressed inflation) which, over time, develops into a monetary overhang: frustrated buying power accumulates over the economy in the form of liquid assets (cash and sight deposits).

Charemza and Gronicki take another approach, using the rational expectations hypothesis to estimate excess demand for consumption and labour both in absolute terms and relative to quantities transacted, the results of which show a U-shaped pattern for excess consumption demand in Poland between 1960 and 1980, bottoming out in 1970, steadily increasing to the mid-1970s at about 8% of total quantity of consumption sales. They also employ a static indicator—the difference between the estimated market-balancing price and the real price—to suggest the strong growth in the level of repressed inflation in Poland after 1970.

From this perspective, macroeconomic rationing—and therefore repressed inflation—is seen as a quintessential and permanent feature of STEs, even in the market for consumer goods. First, because excess purchasing power is often deliberately built into wage settlements by the planners, thus forcing the adjustment process onto consumers; and second, because it is seen as a basis of social discipline (and political power).

The initial criticism of this position must be that visible signs of shortage cannot, without further qualification, be taken as indicators of excess demand at the macroeconomic level. This is because the root causes of the observed phenomena may be microeconomic in character. They might, for example, be the result of inadequacies of distribution rather than production, or they may stem from the rigidities of pricing policy (that is, a problem of relative rather than aggregate prices). These observable indicators may be particularly misleading if we think of repressed inflation as the rate of change of excess demand.

Why do we need to know?
The question of the source of repressed inflation is an important one, as it will influence the choice of stabilisation policies pursued in the period of transition from socialist to capitalist economic systems.

Is aggregation appropriate in STEs?
Within the field, there has been a somewhat heated dispute over the theoretical justification for statistical aggregation, given the nature of Soviet-type economic systems. An example of the aggregative method is an econometric study of Portes and Winter. While arguing that the roots of the problem are microeconomic in character, they maintain the pertinence of a macro approach to an analysis of economic imbalance. They test and reject the hypothesis that excess macroeconomic demand is endemic to the consumer goods markets of STEs. On the contrary, they conclude that from the mid-1950s to the mid-1970s excess supply was the dominant regime in three out of the four countries analysed (Hungary, Poland the GDR and Czechoslovakia).

Kornai, in contrast, contends that in a shortage economy, the idea of excess macroeconomic demand is not an operational category. By this, I think he means that when the consumer is forced to substitute for their original buying intentions, or is deterred from following through the buying intention in any form, the netting out of shortages for some products against surpluses for others is inappropriate, since withdrawal from the market reduces the level of observable shortages; also, perhaps, that quantitative measures fail to take into account qualitative criteria. This may mean that Portes's rhetorical criticism of estimates of excess aggregate labour supply in Western countries because of the phenomenon of the "discouraged worker" may be inadvertently justified.

Holzman's indicator for repressed inflation—the ratio of free market (kolkhoz) prices to state prices for foodstuffs, weighted by share of output and expressed as an index—assumes that the level of repressed inflation in the state sector has a direct impact on the level of prices in the free market. The ratio indicates a decline in the level of repressed inflation in the USSR for the decade after 1955, followed by a period of stability that lasted until the mid-1970s, when a definite, though undramatic, increase occurred until 1979. (However, I couldn’t see from the data what the proportions of the repressed inflation were at the base date.)

It has also been argued that trends in the money-income ratio should be interpreted as a wealth-income ratio in STEs, since the underdevelopment of capital markets means that only a narrow range of assets is available. The trends taken to indicate the development of involuntary saving may therefore be better explained by factors that interpret them as increased rates of voluntary saving. Ofer suggests that two such factors are the need to build up levels of saving: first, to be able to purchase consumer durables when no consumer credit is available; and, second, to offset the deterioration of public services and real levels of social security pay. In addition, a significant rise in the wealth-income ratio is hardly surprising given the very low levels of the ratio that prevailed in many STEs at the beginning of the 1960s. Cotarelli and Blejer suggest that, applying the life cycle hypothesis to consumption behaviour in the USSR, the increase in the wealth-income ratio could be interpreted as resulting from the deceleration of disposable income growth in the period 1965-80.

Conclusions
The hypothesis of endemic repressed inflation in the market for consumer goods thus emerges battered from the criticisms of more nuanced, more plausible interpretations of data and of rigorous econometric analysis. Nuti seems to add to the weight of this criticism by pointing out that the acceleration in the growth of liquid assets could be explained by the higher market-clearing prices on secondary markets, or by the necessity of speculative holdings in conditions of erratic supply—both of which would invalidate the concept of involuntary holdings for the sector as a whole. This might go some way, he suggests, to reconciling the estimates of low overall excess demand in the consumer sphere with concern for market imbalance. However, he goes on to argue that the bulk of the stored up buying power would be pressing on the lower priced, quantity-constrained markets as a result of (I think) the lack of substitutability between (luxury and everyday) goods. Consequently, the level of excess demand could be increasing fast in the state consumption sector, while open inflation in the non-state consumption sector keeps the level of excess demand for the sector overall at a stable level.

2 comments:

Anonymous said...

[url=http://culturadigital.br/longchampsacsa/]sac longchamp[/url] i love this thing!! We Sale Cheap Mulberry Henry Natural Leather Laptop Briefcase Brown for Men,reasonable price in Mulberry Factory Shop. it has tons of pockets everywhere, and the compartment inside is split into two sections. If you have any concerns about your own health or the health of your child, you should always consult with a physician or other healthcare professional. Please review the Privacy Policy and Terms of Use before using this site.
[url=http://longchampbagsd.webeden.net/#/blog/4574070481]sacs longchamps[/url] Then we dumped that portion of popcorn into a paper lunch bag and rolled down the In Vogue Mulberry Women's Bayswater Leather Ostrich Shoulder Red Bag, are believed to be one of the most popular Mulberry Sale with high quality and discount price. top so the popping corn wouldn't escape. This size, 2.6 oz, is important because your microwave oven is already set to pop exactly that much popcorn and do it very well. It's easier than cooking it on the stove and easier than using an air popper!.
[url=http://longchamppliagea.pblogs.gr/]sac longchamp[/url] Any woman who is interested in quality, functionality and affordability should consider a Coach handbag. It is easy to find a less expensive brand that has a bag that may look a lot like a Coach Most Fashionable Mulberry Women's East West Bayswater Leather Shoulder Black Bag on sale,Plus free shipping and no sales tax handbag. However, it's not just style and fashion that are important. In the olden times, brooches are practical goods applied to pin clothes like togas and a lot more. They have been also applied as ornamental jewelry. They were used to adorn kilts, coats, jackets, and even handbags. Ballet flats are a sweet and innocent looking summer steal, even when you sport them in leopard print. These shoes can go from the boardroom to the boardwalk and you'll look great, plus your feet will be thanking you because they're a shoe of such simple construction. Dressed up or down, these shoes are so versatile you truly can wear them anywhere! Not only that, but as graceful and demure as dancers are, it can make you feel very much like the princess when you slip your feet in to them...

Anonymous said...

I apologise that, I can help nothing. But it is assured, that you will find the correct decision.
Your phrase simply excellent
I have thought and have removed the message
Attempt not torture.
I confirm. I agree with told all above. Let's discuss this question. Here or in PM.

[url=http://www.cheapmichaelkors0.350.com/][b]michael kors outlet online[/b][/url]
[url=http://shenenmaoyitt.tumblr.com/][b]michael kors outlet online[/b][/url]
[url=http://shenenmaoyitt.webs.com/][b]michael kors outlet online[/b][/url]
[url=http://shenenmaoyik.futblog.com.br/][b]michael kors outlet online[/b][/url]
[url=http://mvpmichaelkorsoutlet2.manifo.com/][b]michael kors outlet online[/b][/url]